Relationships between economic theory variables and
mathematical instruments for assessing competition conditions
and market power
Relaciones entre las variables de la teoría económica y los
instrumentos matemáticos para evaluar las condiciones de
competencia y el poder de mercado
Fecha de recepción: 15 de marzo de 2024
Fecha de aceptación: 10 de julio de 2024
1
Jacques Lartigue Mendoza
Salomón Domínguez De La Cruz
2
1
Profesor/investigador en la Facultad de Economía y Negocios de la Universidad Anáhuac México, miembro del Sistema
Nacional de Investigadores (SNI) del CONAHCYT y perito para asuntos económicos del Poder Judicial de la Federación en
México. Estudio el doctorado en economía en The State University of New York (SUNY) at Stony Brook y la maestría en
economía en la Universidad de Guadalajara. Correo electrónico: jacques.lartigue@anahuac.mx. ORCID:
https://orcid.org/0000-0001-9741-6851.
Doctor en Ciencias Matemáticas por la Universidad Nacional Autónoma de México y profesor investigador de la Universidad
Anáhuac, México desde 2018. Ha desarrollado investigación teórica en matemáticas abstractas (álgebras de
conglomerados) e investigación en economía aplicada (economía laboral). Sus áreas de interés en economía son inclusión
financiera, economía laboral y competencia económica.. Correo electrónico: salomon.dominguez@anahuac.mx. ORCID:
https://orcid.org/0000-0003-1380-1715.
2
Abstract
The sole existence of a market does not guarantee the maximum level of efficiency and
social welfare it can provide through a competitive structure. As a result, a set of
theoretical relationships and mathematical instruments have been developed to measure
how far existing markets are from being competitive; as well as how much power firms
have for setting prices and earn more than they would do in competitive markets. In this
line, the current paper discusses and integrates diverse theoretical relationships and
mathematical instruments underlying the assessment of competition conditions and
market power and exhibits how the estimation of these instruments can be simplified to
require only two variables: market shares and the price elasticity of demand.
Keywords: Competition conditions; market power; market concentration; competitive
markets.
Resumen
La sola existencia de un mercado no garantiza el máximo nivel de eficiencia y bienestar
social que este puede alcanzar a través de una estructura competitiva. Como resultado, se
han desarrollado un conjunto de relaciones teóricas e instrumentos matemáticos que
permiten cuantificar qué tan lejos están los mercados existentes de ser competitivos, así
como cuánto poder tienen las empresas para fijar precios y ganar más de lo que
obtendrían en mercados competitivos. En este sentido, el presente documento analiza e
integra diversas relaciones teóricas e instrumentos matemáticos que sustentan la
evaluación de las condiciones de competencia y el poder de mercado, y muestra cómo la
estimación de estos instrumentos se puede simplificar para requerir solo dos variables:
participaciones de mercado y elasticidad precio de la demanda.
Palabras claves: Condiciones de competencia; poder de mercado; concentración de
mercado; mercados competitivos.
JEL Classification: D40; L10; L40
Clasificación JEL: D40; L10; L40
Introduction
The existence of a market grants its participants –both consumers and firms– benefits
known as producer and consumer surplus, which sum constitute social welfare[1].
Nevertheless, the sole existence of a market does not guarantee the maximum level of
social welfare, since it may culminate in various structures, such as perfect competition,
monopolistic competition, oligopoly, and monopoly.
1
Consumer surplus –in yellow in Figures 1a, 1b, and 1c– is constituted by the sum –integral with non-linear curves– of the
difference between the price each consumer is willing to pay –a point on the market demand curve– and the price he pays
market price–; producer surplus in blue in Figure 1a and blue plus red in Figures 1b and 1c– is constituted by the sum
integral with non-linear curves of the difference between the cost of producing one unit –a point on the market supply
curve– and the price at which it is sold –market price–.
Among all previous structures, the one that provides the maximum overall sum of benefits
to society, that is the maximum social welfare, is a competitive market. Specifically, as the
level of competition increases in any market the amount of production augments, the
variety and quality of products or services expand, and the prices drop (Biswas &
Koufopoulos, 2020; Broman & Eliasson, 2019; Nie & Yang, 2023). For example, a larger
competition in the banking market promotes an increment in the quality of financial
services, a reduction in their prices, a boost in the proportion of society with access to
these services (Lartigue Mendoza et al., 2020), a larger rate of economic growth, and a
better distribution of income (Abuselidze, 2021; Barra & Zotti, 2019; Hsieh et al., 2019).
With this in mind, the economic science has analysed the existent relationship among
diverse economic variables and developed a set of mathematical instruments that permit
measuring how far existing markets are from being competitive and how much market
power firms have for setting prices above marginal costs in a profitable way; putting it
differently, how much power firms have for choosing a price and earn more than they
would do in a competitive market.
Some of these mathematical instruments have been addressed to measure the level of
concentration, which refers to the number of firms and their relative participation in a given
industry or market. Usually, the more concentrated a market is, the less efficiency and
social welfare it achieves, punishing consumers and rewarding anti-competitive practices.
In this regard, Rodríguez-Castelán et al. (2023) and Liu et al. (2022) argue that a higher
concentration affects negatively firms´ productivity, given that if only a few enterprises
dominate a market the competition is limited, permitting firms to operate with less
pressure for improving their products, services, and processes.
On the other hand, a larger market power provokes a larger loss of consumer surplus
(Adeabah & Andoh, 2019) and therefore it negatively affects social welfare (Aguilar &
Portilla, 2024). For example, when commercial banks hold less market power, borrowers
get better financial services, which is reflected in a larger social welfare (Wei et al., 2024).
Building on all previous arguments, it is in the best interest of market participants and
governments to promote competitive markets, for all traded goods and services in their
economies. Nonetheless, this path is not free of obstacles, being one of them the usual
difficulty or impossibility of obtaining the value of certain variables, which are included in
the formulas of these mathematical instruments, such as marginal costs and input prices.
In this line, the objective of the current paper is to help empirical economists to easily
asses the competition conditions of a given market and the market power of the participant
firms, by both i) explaining the integration of the main economic variables, theoretical
relationships, and mathematical instruments used for this kind of assessment, and ii)
exhibiting how the computation of these mathematical instruments can be simplified to
require only two variables: market shares and the price elasticity of demand.
Methodologically speaking, this research makes a confrontation between economic theory
and diverse technical mathematical instruments required for its application. Along the
same line, it also analyzes and exposes the practical viability of the previous instruments
for assessing competition conditions and market power in any market.
Thus, the questions to be answered by this research are: which theoretical relationships
exist among the variables used for assessing competition conditions and market power?
Given that empirically speaking the values of some variables are difficult to obtain, how
can be reduced the number of variables required by the mathematical instruments used
for estimating market power? Which relationships exist among the mathematical
instruments used for assessing the level of concentration and the market power of a given
firm or industry?
It is worth pointing out that while the discussed theoretical relationships among variables
are considered neoclassical, the mathematical instruments for assessing the
competitiveness of a market were developed in a parallel way during the last century. We
present both the relationships between economic theory variables and mathematical
instruments, as well as the existent relationships among the last ones.
On the other hand, some concentration mathematical instruments constitute special cases
of the general one, such as the case of the instrument presented by Hirschman (1945) and
Herfindahl (1950) some decades before the instrument introduced by Hanna & Kay (1977).
Under certain assumptions, market power mathematical indicators can be derived as
functions of concentration ones; these are the cases of the market power instruments
introduced by Lerner (1934) and Panzar & Rosse (1977), which can be derived as functions
of the concentration instrument presented by Herfindahl and Hirshman.
Analogously, the previous market power indicators -the Lerner index and the Panzar-Rosse
H statistic- can be derived as a function of each other (Shaffer, 1983a). This relationship
can be proved by assuming a Cournot competition with a homogeneous cost function of
degree one, two inputs, a constant price elasticity of demand, and constant marginal costs
(Sanchez-Cartas, 2020) or even with milder assumptions considering the previous ones
but with a cost function of any degree and any amount of inputs (Domínguez & Lartigue-
Mendoza, 2024).
Analogously, the previous market power indicators -the Lerner index and the Panzar-Rosse
H statistic- can be derived as a function of each other (Shaffer, 1983a). This relationship
can be proved by assuming a Cournot competition with a homogeneous cost function of
degree one, two inputs, a constant price elasticity of demand, and constant marginal costs
(Sanchez-Cartas, 2020) or even with milder assumptions considering the previous ones
but with a cost function of any degree and any amount of inputs (Domínguez & Lartigue-
Mendoza, 2024).
Section 2 discusses the aforementioned theoretical relationships; section 3 presents and
analyses the relationships among the most recurrent mathematical instruments for
assessing competition conditions and market power, as well as the techniques for
estimating them; section 4 synthesizes the results; lastly, section 5 concludes.
Theoretical economic relationships
Theoretical relationships among residual demand curve, marginal revenue,
and marginal cost, with competitive and non-competitive markets, national
production level, and income distribution
Regardless of the market structure they belong to, firms’ objective is to maximize benefits,
which can be achieved through two paths. The first one is the usual maximization distance
between revenues and costs, which can be achieved by taking the first derivative of the
profit function –π=pq-cq–2[2] with respect to the control variable (Carlton & Perloff, 2015;
Motta, 2003; Tirole, 1990).
2
Where π = profit; p = price; q = quantity; and c = cost.
There exists a second alternative that provides the same results. This methodology is
based on finding the point at which marginal revenue is identical to marginal cost –point A
in Figures 2a, 2b, and 2c–; this is, the firm will increase the production till the level where
one additional unit generates an additional income equal to the additional cost. Once this
point is located, the firm under perfect competition will know the quantity –Q* in Figure
2c– it must offer, since the market will have already determined the price, and the firm
under any other market structure –unless the firm faces a perfectly elastic demand curve–
will be able to choose the price –P*– or the quantity –Q*– that correspond to this point
Figures 2a and 2b–, and the market, through the residual demand curve[3], will choose the
other variable.
3
Residual demand = market demand – competitors´ supply. This is, it is the demand curve that a firm faces.
It should be noted that in a competitive market the price is determined by the market at the intersection of
the market supply and demand curves –P* in Figure 1a–. This way, a competitive firm, being a price-taker,
will face a horizontal residual demand curve with a price level –P* in Figure 2c– identical to the one
determined by the market.
Figure 1. Consumer and producer surplus, social welfare, and social loss (1).
Figure 2. Non-competitive market with and without barriers to entry and competitive
market (1)
(1)The relationships among the curves of this Figure are discussed all along section two.
Source: Tirole (1994); Carlton & Perloff (2015).
(1)The relationships among the curves of this Figure are discussed all along section two.
Source: Tirole (1994); Carlton & Perloff (2015).
It can be seen, thus, that one of the main determinants of the level of social welfare that a
market will generate is the slope of the residual demand curve a firm faces. If the residual
demand curve of the good or service that a firm produces is horizontal –perfectly elastic–
the price will be given, and increasing the price above market price would translate into the
loss of all its customers. In this case, the price will be the lowest and the quantity the
highest possible of any market structure, with these results corresponding to a perfectly
competitive market structure –Figure 1a–, reaching the maximum level of social welfare
that a market can breed.
On the other hand, a residual demand curve with a negative slope, which can be originated
from the lack of enough competitors in the market or the existence of differentiated goods,
allows the firm to set the price above the marginal cost in a profitable way; this is known as
market power and can be measured by using mathematical indicators as the Lerner index
–(price–marginal cost)/price–.
Given that the supply curve is nothing more than the section of the marginal cost curve that
has a positive slope beginning from the average variable cost curve, setting the price above
the marginal cost –before the supply curve intersects with the residual demand curve–
means necessarily shrinking the supply in comparison to a perfectly competitive market
where the price will be equal to the marginal cost–.
In general terms, provided that there are no large economies of scale, which can cause
natural monopolies or oligopolies, the lack of barriers to entry –the free entry and exit of
firms– will lead firms’ profits to equal zero, regardless of whether the firm faces a residual
demand curve with a negative slope or not.
We can then notice that a non-competitive market engenders two costs to society: a) the
obtaining of a smaller production level –GDP–, generating a reduction in the level of social
welfare, known as social loss –green triangles in Figures 1b and 1c–; and, b) a worsening of
the income distribution, given that by placing the price above the competitive price a part
of the consumer surplus is redistributed among the producers –red rectangles in Figures
1b and 1c–, who will increase their surplus –the aggregate sum of their economic rents–,
thus obtaining more benefits than they would under a competitive market. In other words,
a non-competitive market reallocates a fraction of the benefits belonging to milliards or
millions of consumers to only a few business owners.
Relevance and relationship between barriers to entry and profitability
It is worth noting that, in economic terms, a profit equal to zero means that the payment
the owners of a given firm receive for the use of the production factors they provide to the
firm is the market value of the same. In other words, a profit equal to zero means that total
revenues are equal to total costs, and that among the latter are considered –at market
value– the interest for the invested capital, the rent corresponding to any asset made
available to the firm –real estate, machinery, etcetera–, and the wage of all the firm’s
workers, including its owners.
This way, given that through their inclusion within the costs the owners are fairly paid –at
market value– for the production factors they make available to the firm, any additional
profit –profit greater than zero– is known as an economic rent.
The discussion in the last three paragraphs can be observed in Figures 2a and 2b. Figure
2a may be used to illustrate both the short run of a firm in a market without barriers to
entry and the long run of a firm in a market with barriers to entry. Concerning the long run,
it is clear that the firm represented in Figure 2a does not belong to a competitive market,
given that it faces a residual demand curve with a negative slope; has market power, since
it can set the price above the marginal cost –point C is above point A–; and, captures rents,
represented by the area of the rectangle with vertices on points B, C, D, and E.
With firms having free entry and exit, the existence of rents displayed in Figure 2a will
appeal new firms, causing the residual demand curve, along with the corresponding
marginal revenue curve, to shift to the left. This is because the more competition there is,
keeping everything else constant, the less the firm will sell at any price. This can be seen in
Figure 2b.
This way, even in a non-competitive market, when there exists free entry and exit of firms,
two conditions are fulfilled in the long run –conditions that are fulfilled both in the long and
short run in a competitive market–: a) the marginal cost is equal to –intersects– the
marginal revenue –point A in Figures 2b and 2c–, and b) the average total cost curve is
tangent to the residual demand curve –point B in Figure 2b and point A in Figure 2c–.
Thus, the obtaining of economic rents for a long period is a sign of the existence of barriers
to entry –large economies of scale are considered natural barriers to entry–. In the
following section, we present how competition conditions and market power can be easily
estimated through mathematical indicators and the relationships among them.
The assessment of competition conditions is composed of a mixture of mathematical
indicators, graphs, and intuitive discussion; all of them usually supported by the economic
theory and relationships above discussed.
Most recurrent mathematical instruments for assessing
competition conditions and market power
How profitable is a market is typically assessed through the Return to Equity –ROE– and
Return to Assets –ROA– indicators. How well distributed among firms is the production
and/or sales of goods or services in a given –relevant– market is assessed by concentration
indicators. Lastly, how much command a firm has for setting prices above marginal costs,
permitting the obtainment of economic rents, is measured by market power indicators. The
last two kinds of indicators, and the relationships among them, are discussed in this
section.
Concentration indicators
There exist several indexes that measure the concentration level in any given market. The
most recurrent ones are the Concentration Ratio –CR–, the Hannah Kay Index, and the
Herfindahl-Hirschman Index ––; being the last one the standard measure in empirical
research.
The Concentration Ratio
The Concentration Ratio –CR– measures the joint market share of the main firms; this way,
CR considers the three main firms and CR the main four; thus, the concentration ratio for k
main firms is defined as
3 4
Where represents the market share of firm with values between 0 and 100.
The U.S. Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission (2010) state market
concentration can be classified according to the following ranges for CR :
4
Perfect competition CR =01.
Effective competition or monopolistic competition 0<CR ≤40.2.
Loose oligopoly or Monopolistic competition 40<CR ≤60.3.
Tight oligopoly or dominant firm with a competitive fringe CR ≤60.4.
4
4
4
4
One of the main criticisms to this indicator points out that it does not distinguish among the
possible market share distributions of the m participant firms. For example, consider
markets A and B, with the following market share distributions for the main four
enterprises: market A with 40%, 20%, 10%, and 10%, and market B with 20% for each
firm. In both CR =80, although, evidently, market B is less concentrated.
4
The Herfindahl-Hirschman Index
The HHI formula is determined by the equation
As it may be seen in the preceding formula, the HHI is the sum of the squared market share
of each firm in the market under study. However, it may also be read as a weighted average
of the market shares of these firms, which assigns a greater weight to larger market
shares. This index may take values between 0 and 10,000, with a larger number meaning a
greater market concentration.
Where represents the market share of firm with values between 0 and 100.
According to the U.S. Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission (2010),
market concentration can be determined using the following HHI ranges.
Deconcentrated 0 ≤ HHI < 15001.
Moderately concentrated 1500 ≤ HHI ≤ 25002.
Highly concentrated 2500 < HHI3.
Market power, understood as the ability to set the price above marginal cost in a profitable
way, can be measured through the Lerner index (1934) and the Panzar-Rosse H statistic
(1977), although the last one has been subject to different critiques.
One of the main criticisms to this index is the requirement of having market share
information about all participant enterprises in the analyzed market (Busu, 2020; Peleckis,
2022a, 2022b).
The Hanna Kay Index
The Hanna-Kay index is defined as
Thus, it is possible to observe that the HHI is a special case of the Hannah Kay Index when
β=2.
Market Power Indicators
The Lerner Index and its relationship with market shares and the price elasticity of
demand
The Lerner index is defined as
where p represents the price of a good and c^' its marginal cost. Within competitive
markets price equals marginal cost –point A in Figure 2c–, therefore the Lerner index L
total zero. The larger the market power a firm has, the greater the distance between price
–point C in Figure 2a– and marginal cost –point A in Figure 2a–, with the Lerner index
being closer to one.
Dickson (1979) showed, by assuming firms follow a Cournot strategic behaviour, the
Lerner Index of enterprise i can be written as
It is possible to observe on the right-hand side of equation (5) that the market power a firm
possesses is an increasing function of its market share –α_i– and a decreasing one of the
industry price elasticity of demand –ε_pQ–.
Multiplying both sides of equation (5) by α_i and taking the sum over all firms, that is using
each firm’s market share as a weight for obtaining a weighted average market power, it is
possible to observe that there exists a relationship between market power, the HHI, and
the market price elasticity of demand
Thus, the weighted average of the power to establish the price above the marginal cost
measured through the Lerner index–, observed in the totality of a market, increases with
market concentration –measured with the HHI and decreases with the market price
elasticity of demand.
Given the constraints to obtain information on firms’ marginal cost, using the right-hand
side of equations (5) and (6) permits estimating the individual firms' as well as the
weighted average market power observed in the whole market, respectively.
The Panzar–Rosse H statistic
Panzar and Rosse introduced a competition indicator that captures firm´s revenue
sensitivity to input prices. The indicator is defined as the sum of gross revenue elasticities
with respect to input prices
where Ψ stands for the Panzar–Rosse H statistic, w_i for input price i, , and R for the
revenue of the firm.
Shaffer (1983) showed that with stable residual demand curves –that is in the short run,
when entry or exit of firms into the market do not occur as a response to changes in input
prices–, there exists a relationship between the Lerner index of an individual firm i and its
H statistics.
Moreover, Shaffer showed that under the Cournot assumption the industry Lerner index
L– can be estimated through where H is the Herfindahl-Hirschman index
and the market share of firm i. Alternatively, if firms collude perfectly the relationship
becomes more straightforward .
On the other hand, by assuming a Cournot competition with a homogeneous cost function
of degree one, two input factors, a constant price elasticity of demand, and constant
marginal costs, Sanchez-Cartas (2020) showed that the Panzar-Rosse H statistics can be
easily estimated once the Lerner index is obtained.
Although the Panzar–Rosse H Statistic has been used as a market power indicator in
diverse research, it has received different critiques related to the range of its possible
values (Almendárez Carreón & Arteaga García, 2020; Canta et al., 2023; Cruz-García et al.,
2021) and the fact that it works more like a competition indicator than a market power one
(Sanchez-Cartas, 2020).
Empirically speaking, the results of the current research exhibit, in section 3, how to
simplify the estimation of the main mathematical indicators used for assessing the
competition conditions and the market power of a given firm, industry, or market.
Permitting, this way, to avoid the requirement of certain variables whose values are very
difficult to obtain for empirical researchers and regulatory institutes, as marginal costs and
input prices.
Specifically, we show how with only market shares it is possible to estimate concentration
indicators, as the Concentration Ratio, the Herfindahl-Hirshman Index, and the Hannah-
Kay Index. If the researcher gets a second variable, the price elasticity of demand, she can
also estimate market power indicators, under certain assumptions, as the Lerner Index
and the Panzar-Rosse H statistic.
Results
Conclutions
This paper discusses the theoretical relationships that exist among the residual demand
curve, marginal revenue, marginal cost, barriers to entry, slope of the residual demand curve,
and price elasticity of demand, that determine if a market is competitive or not, and the
social welfare it provides. Additionally, it integrates concentration and market power
indicators into the discussed theory and resumes how they can be easily estimated.
The presented theoretical discussion concludes that if a firm holds market power, that is, the
capacity to set the price above the marginal cost in a profitable manner, two conditions are
fulfilled: a) it faces a residual demand curve with a negative slope; and, b) there exist barriers
to entry. Thus, theoretically speaking, the attainment of economic rents for a prolonged
period can be considered as an indicator of the existence of barriers to entry and market
power.
While concentration indicators are functions of firms market shares, we present under which
assumptions market power indicators can be simplified to functions of market shares and
the industry price elasticity of demand, permitting their computation with only these two
inputs.
Abuselidze, G. (2021). The impact of banking competition on economic growth and
financial stability: An empirical investigation. European Journal of Sustainable
Development, 10(1), 203. https://doi.org/10.14207/ejsd.2021.v10n1p203
Adeabah, D., & Andoh, C. (2019). Market power, efficiency and welfare performance of
banks: Evidence from the Ghanaian banking industry.
https://hdl.handle.net/10419/192967
Aguilar, G., & Portilla, J. (2024). Market power, social welfare, and efficiency in the
Peruvian microfinance. Economia Politica, 41(1), 123–152.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s40888-023-00321-y
Almendárez Carreón, Ó. I., & Arteaga García, J. C. (2020). Medición del grado de
competencia en el mercado de Afores: La aplicación del enfoque no paramétrico de la
NOIE. Revista de Economía, Facultad de Economía, Universidad Autónoma de Yucatán,
37(95), 30–49. https://doi.org/10.33937/reveco.2020.145
Barra, C., & Zotti, R. (2019). Bank performance, financial stability and market
concentration: Evidence from cooperative and noncooperative banks. Annals of Public and
Cooperative Economics, 90(1), 103–139. https://doi.org/10.1111/apce.12217
Biswas, S. (Sonny), & Koufopoulos, K. (2020). Bank competition and financing efficiency
under asymmetric information. Journal of Corporate Finance, 65.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2019.101504
Broman, E., & Eliasson, J. (2019). Welfare effects of open access competition on railway
markets. Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice, 129, 72–91.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tra.2019.07.005
Busu, M. (2020). A market concentration analysis of the biomass sector in Romania.
Resources, 9(6). https://doi.org/10.3390/RESOURCES9060064
References
Canta, C., Nilsen, Ø. A., & Ulsaker, S. A. (2023). Competition and risk taking in local bank
markets: Evidence from the business loans segment. Journal of Empirical Finance, 73,
153–169. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jempfin.2023.06.003
Carlton, D. W., & Perloff, J. M. (2015). Modern industrial organization. Global Edition.
Cruz-García, P., Fernández de Guevara, J., & Maudos, J. (2021). Bank competition and
multimarket contact intensity. Journal of International Money and Finance, 113.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2020.102338
Dickson, V. A. (1979). The Lerner index and measures of concentration. Economics Letters,
3(3), 275–279. https://doi.org/10.1016/0165-1765(79)90131-9
Domínguez, S., & Lartigue-Mendoza, J. (2024). The Lerner index and the H-statistics of
Panzar-Rosse, relationship and estimation under mild assumptions.
https://doi.org/0.2139/ssrn.4763489
Hanna, L., & Kay, J. A. (1977). Concentration in modern industry.
Herfindahl, O. C. (1950). Concentration in the steel industry. In Columbia University (Issue
June).
Hirschman, Albert. O. (1945). National power and the structure of foreign trade (P.
University of California, Ed.).
Hsieh, J., Chen, T.-C., & Lin, S.-C. (2019). Financial structure, bank competition and income
inequality. The North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 48, 450–466.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2019.03.006
Lartigue Mendoza, J., Ayala Navarro, K., & Sauri Alpuche, G. (2020). Competition
conditions and market power in the Mexican commercial banking market. A
microeconomic theoretical approach. Revista Finanzas y Política Económica, 12(2), 367–
402. https://doi.org/10.14718/revfinanzpolitecon.v12.n2.2020.2814
Lerner, A. P. (1934). The concept of monopoly and the measurement of monopoly power.
Review of Economic Studies, 1(3), 157–175. https://doi.org/10.2307/2967480
Liu, E., Mian, A., & Sufi, A. (2022). Low interest rates, market power, and productivity
growth. Econometrica, 90(1), 193–221. https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA17408
Motta, M. (2003). Competition policy: Theory and practice.
Nie, P., & Yang, Y. (2023). Innovation and competition with human capital input.
Managerial and Decision Economics, 44(3), 1779–1785.
https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.3782
Panzar, J. C., & Rosse, J. N. (1977). Chamberlin vs. Robinson : an empirical test for
monopoly rents. In Studies in Industry Economics no. 77 (Stanford University, Stanford
CA).
Peleckis, K. (2022a). Application of the multicriteria method seeking to assess
concentration, and its effects on competition in the manufacturing sector. Sustainability
(Switzerland), 14(19). https://doi.org/10.3390/su141912062
Peleckis, K. (2022b). Determining the level of market concentration in the construction
sector-case of application of the HHI index. Sustainability (Switzerland), 14(2).
https://doi.org/10.3390/su14020779
Rodríguez-Castelán, C., López-Calva, L. F., & Barriga-Cabanillas, O. (2023). Market
concentration, trade exposure, and firm productivity in developing countries: Evidence
from Mexico. World Development, 165. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2023.106199
Sanchez-Cartas, J. M. (2020). The Panzar-Rosse H Statistic and Monopoly. Issues on its
Use as a Market Power Measure. B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy, 20(4).
https://doi.org/10.1515/bejeap-2020-0193
Shaffer, S. (1983a). The Rosse-Panzar statistic and the Lerner index in the short run*.
Economics Letters, 11, 175–178. https://doi.org/10.1016/0165-1765(83)90181-7
Shaffer, S. (1983b). The Rosse-Panzar statistic and the Lerner index in the short run.
Economics Letters, 11(1–2), 175–178. https://doi.org/10.1016/0165-1765(83)90181-7
Tirole, J. (1990). The theory of industrial organization. In Journal of Political Economy (Vol.
98, Issue 3, pp. 668–671). https://doi.org/10.1086/261701
U.S. Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission. (2010). Horizontal merger
guidelines U.S. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01034180
Wei, Q., Zeng, S., & Tao, Q. (2024). Does bank competition improve borrower welfare?
Evidence from China. Economic Analysis and Policy, 82, 1353–1368.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eap.2024.05.015